辅导案例-WP-75-4

欢迎使用51辅导,51作业君孵化低价透明的学长辅导平台,服务保持优质,平均费用压低50%以上! 51fudao.top
OPTIMAL HARVEST STRATEGIES FOR SALMON IN
RELATION TO ENVIRONMENTAL VARIABILITY AND
UNCERTAINTY ABOUT PRODUCTION PARAMETERS*
Carl J. Walters**
January 1975 WP-75-4
*Research supported by Environment Canada
and by the International Institute for
Applied Systems Analysis.
** Institute of Animal Resource Ecology,
The University of British Columbia.
Working Papers are not intended for
distribution outside of IIASA, and
are solely for discussion and infor-
mation purposes. The views expressed
are those of the author, and do not
necessarily reflect those of IIASA.
RM-77-2
LINKING NATIONAL MODELS OF FOOD AND AGRICULTURE:
An Introduction
M.A. Keyzer
January 1977
Research Memoranda are interim reports on research being con-
ducted by the International Institt;te for Applied Systems Analysis,
and as such receive only limited scientifk review. Views or opin-
ions contained herein do not necessarily represent those of the
Institute or of the National Member Organizations supporting the
Institute.
ii
Abstract
A method is developed for incorporating the effects
of environmental variability and judgmental uncertainty
about future production parameters into the design of
optimal harvest strategies, expressed as curves relating
stock size and exploitation rate. For the Skeena River Sock-
eye, the method suggests that optimal strategies are in-
sensitive to judgmental uncertainty about the Ricker
Stock production parameter, but are very sensitive to
management objectives related to the mean' and variance
of catches. Best possible tradeoffs between mean and
variance of catches for the Skeena River are developed
and a simplified strategy is suggested for improving
mean catch while reducing year to year variation.
1. Introduction
Pacific Salmon management in recent years has been based
on the concept that maximum sustained yield can be obtained
by holding escapements at some constant level determined by
analysis of the stock-recruitment relationship. Larkin and
Ricker (1964), and Tautz, Larkin, and Ricker (1969) showed
that such fixed escapement strategies should result in higher
mean yields than fixed exploitation rate strategies in the
face of high stochastic variation in productivity. However,
Allen (1973) has stressed the need to look at other possible
management strategies expressed as relationships between har-
vest and stock size; he shows for the Skeena River that fixed
escapement strategies should result in unnecessarily high var-
iance in catches from year to year, and he develops alterna-
tive relationships that should cut the variance of catches
nearly in half with only about a 15% reduction in mean catch.
-2-
The intent of this paper is to present a set of optimal
harvest strategies for salmon, based on tradeoffs between the
mean and variance of catches. The Skeena River is used as an
example, and the optimal strategies are developed by using
stochastic dynamic programming. This formidable sounding op-
timization technique is actually a relatively simple method
for testing the multitude of possible future stock changes
that harvest and environmental variability may produce, weight-
ing each future change by its probability of occurrence.
Since the technique has seen little application in biol-
ogy, section II gives an intuitive introduction to stochastic
dynamic programming. Section III presents a variety of harvest
strategies for the Skeena River, under different assumptions
about environmental variability and using different management
objectives, and examines possible management strategies in
relation to current management practice on the Skeena River.
Section IV analyses potential tradeoffs between mean and var-
iance of catches, and suggests an overall optimal strategy
for the Skeena River. Hopefully it is demonstrated that op-
timal management policies should bear no clear relationship
either to the current (fixed escapement) practice or to the
strategy alternatives suggested by Allen (1973).
II Stochastic Dynamic Programming
The basic concept of dynamic programming was introduced
by Richard Bellman in the 1940's (See Bellman, 1961; Bellman
-3-
and Dreyfus, 1962; Bellman and Kalaba, 1965). It is an op-
timization technique for systems in which a series of deci-
sions must be made in sequence, where each decision affects
the subsequent system state and thus each future decision.
Two key ingredients are necessary to apply the method: a
dynamic model to predict the next state of the system given
any starting state and any decision, and an objective func-
tion to specify the value of the return obtained in one time
step for any state-decision combination. In stochastic prob-
lems, the dynamic model must specify not a single future state
but instead must specify probabilities for each new state that
might arise after one time step from any starting state-de-
cision combination.
The dynamic model
Following most authors on salmon management theory, the
simple Ricker model is used in this study as the necessary
dynamic model:
[~
where
Nt +l = Stock (recruitment) after one generation, in
standard stock units (approximately 2,000,000
for Skeena Sockeye)
St = Escapement or spawing population, in stock units
a = stock production parameter, assumed to be a random
variable.
-4-
aIf St is held fixed, e represents the net stock productivity
or recruitment excess. This factor arises in nature as a pro-
duct of several survival factors that vary randomly but may
be considered more or less independent of one another. Thus,
a, the logarithm of e a is a sum of random variables and should
be normally distributed by the Central Limit Theorem of basic
statistics. Allen (1973) provides good empirical justification
for this assumption using data from the Skeena River.
is written as
o < u t < 0 1.0 [~
where u t is the exploitation rate, or decision variable, then
we have the first basic ingredient for dynamic programming.
The objective is to find an optimal relationship between u
t
and Nt' by examining sequences of decisions where the next
state arising from any Nt - u t combination is predicted with
the Ricker model using an appropriate probability distribution
for a.
As an alternative to the Ricker model, we could simply
specify a separate empirical or judgmental probability distri-
bution of recruitment for each conceivable spawing stock (in
other words, treat the stock-recruitment relationship as a
Markov process). However, even for the Skeena River Sockeye
there is insufficient data to meaningfully interpolate recruit-
ment probabilities for high and low spawning stocks (Figure 1).
-5-
The Ricker model appears to be as good a way as any for extra-
polation to extreme stock sizes.
The objective function
The other basic ingredient, the objective function, may
take a variety of forms. For maximizing mean harvest, we can
take it to be simply u t .Nt . If variance is important, we can
instead try to minimize the variance around some desired catch
level; for each time step the relative contribution to variance
is then
24.I ·N - jJ)t t
where jJ is the desired catch level. Note that if jJ is arbi-
trarily increased to high values that cannot be achieved in
nature, the variance contribution at each step becomes essen-
tially linear in Ut"Nt . This means mathematically that mini-
mizing the sum over time of squared deviations from high jJ val-
ues tends toward being equivalent to maximizing UtN t , as jJ is
increased. Thus by changing jJ we can generate a series of
objective functions that range from variance-minimizing to har-
vest maximizing as jJ is increased (this point will be clarified
in Section IV).
The computational procedure
Given the basic ingredients above, the next step required
for dynamic programming is to approximate the continuous var-
iables u t ' Nt and a by a series of discrete, representative
-6-
levels or states. The concept here is the same as is used in
solving differential equations by taking short discrete time
steps. By trial and error, it was found necessary for this
study to use 30 discrete population levels, each representing
an increment of .05 stock units (Nt = 0.0,0.05, 0.1, ... ,1.45),
30 discrete exploitation rates at intervals of 0.03 (Ut = 0.0,
0.03,0.06, ... ,0.82), and 10 discrete a values (a discretization
will be presented in Section III) .
The reader is referred to figure 2 for the following ex-
planation. Suppose we look at any discrete stock size at some
time step, and think about applying many possible harvest
rates to it (left hand "decision branches" in Figure 2). For
each harvest rate a return (harvest or contribution to variance)
can be computed, but the recruitment subsequently resulting
from this escapement will be uncertain (right hand "probability
branches" in Figure 2). Suppose that we specify probabilities
for each possible new stock size that might be produced, and
suppose that we already know (somehow) what future returns can
be expected for each of these new stock sizes. Then for each
harvest rate, we can find an expected overall value: it is
simply the return this year, plus the sum of products of pro-
babilities of getting new stock sizes times the expected fu-
ture returns for these new sizes. In other words, we take
each possible future and weight it by its probability of
occurrence to give an expected value for future returns; this
expected future value is added to this year's return to give
-7-
the overall value for the harvest rate-present stock combina-
tion, for the particular time step under consideration. The
process can be repeated for each possible harvest rate, and
afterwards it is a simple matter to choose which rate gives the
best overall return.
We can next choose another stock size, and try many pos-
sible harvest rates on it. Again providing that we already
know what future returns can be expected for each new stock
size that might result, and that we can associate a probability
with each possibility, it is a simple matter to choose the
best harvest rate for this second stock size.
The whole process is repeated for a third stock size, a
fourth, and so on until the optimal harvest rate for every
reasonable stock size has been computed. The result is a set
of stock-harvest combinations that can be plotted against one
another as a smooth curve; this curve is called the optimal
control law for the time step under consideration.
The real trick in dynamic programming is to get the ex-
pected future returns Eoreach new stock size that can result
for each startingu t - Nt combination. This trick, the key
discovery of Richard Bellman, is remarkably simple: we work
backwards in time from an arbitrary end point (t = K). Values
are assigned to different stock sizes at this endpoint, and
these values are used to look ahead at the endpoint from one
time step backward (t = K - 1). After getting overall values
for each stock size one step back from the endpoint, we can
-8-
then move back another step (t K - 2), and look ahead to the
values just computed for t = K - 1. This backward recursion
process is repeated over and over (t = k - 3, K - 4, etc.)
After several backward recursion steps, a phenomenon
emerges that forms the central basis for this paper: the
endpoint values cease to have any effect, and the optimal ex-
ploitation rate for each stock size becomes independent of the
time step. The optimal control law or harvest strategy curve
is then said to have stabilized; this usually occurs within
10 - 20 steps for the Ricker model. Certain computational
tricks are necessary to insure that the stable control law is
valid, since the new stocks produced at each forward look may
not correspond exactly to any that have already been examined
for the next time step forward. This interpolation problem
is solved by being careful to examine enough discretized stock
sizes and exploitation rates.
The key feature of stochastic dynamic programming is that
it explicitly takes account of all the possible futures that
are considered likely enough to be assigned probabilities of
occurrence. Furthermore, it makes no difference whether these
probabilities are chosen to represent judgmental uncertainty
(Raiffa, 1968) about deterministic parameters, or true sto-
chastic variation in parameter values, or some combination of
these sources of uncertainty.
III Optimal Strategy Examples
This section develops a set of judgmental probability
-9-
distributions for the a parameter of equation 1, using the
Skeena River Sockeye as an example. These probability dis-
tributions are then used to demonstrate the form of optimal
harvest curves obtained by the procedures outlined above, for
different objective functions. Simulation results are pre-
sented to show the likely consequences of applying the harvest
curves, in terms of probability distributions of catches and
stock sizes. Finally, alternative harvest curves are compared
to actual management practice on the Skeena River.
a distributions for the Skeena River
Using the data in Figure 1, a set of empirical a values
can be computed as
where i is the data point
R., S. are the recruitment and spawner values
1 1
Se is the replacement number of spawners in the
absence of harvest.
S was taken to be 2,000,000 spawners, and the results for a
e
are presented in Figure 3, top panel. As Ricker (1973) points
out, there has been a decrease in the mean value of a in recent
years. With some imagination, one might conclude that the
frequencies had been drawn from a normal distribution; luckily,
no such assumption is necessary in order to apply stochastic
dynamic programming.
-10-
The bottom panel of Figure 3 shows three judgmental pro-
bability distributions that a decision maker might draw after
examining the top panel. These test distributions are all
truncated at 0 and 2.3, for computational convenience (test
runs showed that extreme values have little effect for the
present problem). The distribution marked "pessimistic"
(for obvious reasons) assumes an even distribution of a val-
ues in the future. The distribution marked "natural" is the
author's artistic (?) rendition of the data, weighting recent
years more heavily. The "optimistic" distribution might be
drawn by a decision maker who believes that the good produc-
tion rates of recent years (Figure 1) will continue in the
future due to better management practices of some sort. An
important concept behind these distributions is that the
stochastic dynamic programming solution can be made to take
a variety of intuitive judgments into account,. beyond the
hard facts of past observations.
Form of the optimal solution
The judgmental probability distributions in Figure 3,
combined with equations (1) and (2) and with several objective
functions, were used to obtain a variety of optimal solutions.
For the computer freaks, I used a PDP 11/45; each solution
required about 100 sec of computer time (30 Nt levels x 30 u t
levels x 10 probability levels x 20 time steps). The discrete
Nt - u t optimal solutions were connected as smooth curves for
presentation here.
-11-
Let us first examine the dome shaped band of optimal
harvest curves indicated by horizontal shading in Figure 4.
All three curves were generated by trying to minimize the
2
objective function (H .6), that is by trying to minimize
the variance of catches around a mean value of 0.6 million
fish. The top curve represents the strategy that should be
followed if the optimistic probability curve for a (Figure 3)
is considered best; the lower two curves represent optimal
strategies for the natural and pessimistic a probabilities
of Figure 3, respectively. The most important conclusion to
be drawn from these curves is that the optimal strategy (for
minimizing (H - .6)2) is quite insensitive to the judgmental
probability distribution for a, except when stock size is between
0.4 and 1.0 million fish. In hindsight, it is easy to give
intuitive reasons for the shapes of the curves: very low
stocks should not be fished since recovery will be showed, and
high stocks should be fished lightly so as to avoid high,
variance-generating catche& An assumption of the Ricker curve
becomes important for high stock sizes, namely that large num-
bers of spawners will not result in very low recruitment in
later years.
Similar results are obtained for the objective of trying
to minimize the variance of catches around a mean value of
1.0 million fish (vertical shaded curves in Figure 4). Again
the prediction is that low stocks should not be fished at all,
while high stocks should receive moderate exploitation.
-12-
The most interesting curves in Figure 4 are for the max-
imum harvest objective function. These curves essentially
call for a constant escapement of around 0.8 - 1.0 million
spawners, as suggested by earlier authors. Also, the optimal
strategy is almost independent of the judgmental probability
distribution for a. In other words, current management pol-
ices on the Skeena River should result, if they can be fol-
lowed, in maximum average catches even if the future distri-
bution of a values is quite different from what it has been.
Predicted catch and stock size distribution
Since the stochastic optimal solutions are based on the
assumption that there is no certain future population trend,
the anticipated returns by applying them are best presented as
probability distributions. The simplest way to approximate
these distributions is by making very long simulation runs,
using equations (1) and (2), with an appropriate random number
generation procedure for a values.
Figure 5 presents catch distributions from 5000 year
simulation trials, for the optimal harvest curves from Figure 4
that should be used if the "natural" a distribution is con-
sidered most credible. Results are also presented for a har-
vest curve shown in Figure 7, that was obtained by trying to
minimize the variance of catches around a mean value (not
achievable) of 2.0 million fish. The results in the top
panel of Figure 5 were generated by actually using the "na-
tural" distribution to choose different a values for each
-13-
simulated year; the results in the bottom panel were generated
by choosing a values from a normal distribution with mean 1.3
and standard deviation 0.5 (after Allen, 1973). The results
are quite similar, again suggesting that the optimal strategies
should be insensitive to the realized future distribution of
a values. The roughness of the curves for the "natural" a
distribution is due to the numerical approximation procedure
used in the simulation program.
Thereshould be an additional benefit from the variance-
minimizing strategies, as shown in Figure 6. The variance of
recruitment stock sizes increases progressively, and the mean
stock size decreases for strategies that place more emphasis
on maximizing mean catch. This is a surprising result, since
the catch maximizing strategies tend to produce stabilized
escapements.
Comparison to actual Management Practice
Catch and escapment statistics kindly provided by F. E.
A. Wood, Environment Canada, were used to compute actual har-
vest rates for the Skeena River Sockeye (Figure 7). It is
apparent that management practice in recent years has been
able to follow the best fixed escapement policy quite closely.
The optimal harvest curves in Figure 7 (all for "natural" a
assumption) represent a spectrum of possible objectives based
on trying to minimize the variance of catches around a series
of increasing values.
Forthe 15 year period before 1970, Figure 7 suggests that
-14-
management practice more closely followed a strategy of trying
to minimize the variance of catches. The correlation could be
purely spurious, but it is tempting to speculate. Management de-
cisions are open to pressure from the industry to allow higher
catches in low stock years, and the industry may be unwilling
to accept excessively high catches in the good years. If fish-
ing decisions have been affected in these ways in recent years,
one wonders about the wisdom of pursuing fixed escapement po-
licies. This question is the central topic of the following
$ection.
IV Tradeoffs between Mean and Variance of Catches
The results in Allen (1973) and Figures 5 and 6 clearly
suggest that management strategies can be devised to signifi-
cantly reduce the variance of catches without intolerable losses
in average yield. The aim of this section is to quantify the
best possible tradeoff relationship between mean and variance
of catches, so that the question of what is "intolerable" can
be subjected to open negotiation. This analysis leads to a
simplified optimal harvest law that can be practically imple-
mented as an alternative to fixed escapement policies.
Definition: The Pareto Frontier
It is necessary to introduce a concept at this point that
may be unfamiliar. Suppose one picks a value for the variance
of catches, and then asks for the maximum mean catch that can
be obtained at this level of variance. Presumably.there is
some answer to this question, and some optimal harvest strategy
-15-
that will do the job. One can then pick another variance val-
ue and ask the same question about mean catch. If one demands
0.0 variance in catches from the Skeena River, then the maximum
mean catch is not likely to exceed about 0.4 million. On the
other hand, if one says that any variance is tolerable, then
he can be presented with the maximum harvest strategy from
Figure 7 with its associated mean value. The set of variance-
mean combinations that can be generated in this way is known
as a Pareto Frontier. In any decision problem where there
are tradeoffs between different kinds of benefits, the highest
achievable combinations are said to define the Pareto Frontier.
Presumably the only management strategies worth considering are
those which generate points along the frontier.
The variance minimizing objective functions used to obtain
the harvest curves of Figure 4 and 7 are asking essentially the
same questions, but in reverse; for any desired mean value, they
ask for a minimum variance harvest curve. Unfortunately, sto-
chastic dynamic programming does not permit us to ask the ques-
tions the other way around without doing excessive additional
computation. As we ask for higher and higher mean values with
the variance-minimizing objective functions, the optimal solu-
tions place more and more weight on getting higher catches, and
correspondingly less on reducing variation (which is always
large if the desired mean value is impossibly high).
-16-
Application to the Skeena River Sockeye
Thus the harvest strategies in Figure 7 should generate
(approximately) values along the mean-variance Pareto Frontier.
Figure 8 presents this frontier for two possible a distribu-
tions. Points along the upper frontier were obtained by 5000
year simulations with "natural" a probabilities and associated
optimal harvest curves, while points along the lower frontier
were obtained by simulating with the pessimistic a probabili~
ties and their associated harvest curves. Observed catch-
variance combinations for the past two decades have been well
below the potential suggested by the "natural" a distribution.
Since the catch-variance combination since 1960 has been well
above the pessimistic frontier, and stocks have increased
steadily over this period, the pessimistic frontier is clearly
too conservative. The main suggestion of Figure 8 is that the
average catch of the past decade could be either:
(1) maintained with an extreme reduction in variance
(using an (H - .8)2 strategy curve)
(2) increased by 25% (0.2 million fish) while maintaining
the same variance (using an (H - 2)2 strategy curve)
(3) or increased by (perhaps) 39% (0.3 million fish)
while increasing the variance by about 50%.
The average catch over the 1970-1974 period has actually been
around 0.9 million fish, as it should be according to figure 8,
but a variance estimate for this short period would hardly be
meaningful.
-17-
A simplified strategy for practical implementation
The optimal ~trategy curves based on variance minimization
would be difficult to implement in practice, since they call
for very good control of annual exploitation rates. Figure 7
suggests that such control is not yet available, even if it
were possible to negotiate a best point along the Pareto Fron-
tier of Figure 8. Thus a simplified strategy is suggested in
Figure 7. This strategy recommends to:
(1) take no harvest from stocks less than 0.5 million
fish
(2) use exploitation rates between 0 and 50% for stocks
between 0.5 and 1.0 million fish
(3) use a 50% exploitation rate for all stock size
above 1.0 million.
This strategy should result in a mean-variance combina-
tion (Figure 8 and 9) nearly on the frontier of best possible
combinations, with a mean catch (0.94 million fish) near the
1970-74 observed average and a 20% reduction in variance from
the 1955-1974 average. By calling for a fixed exploitation
rate (and thus fixed effective fishing effort) most of the
time, the simplified strategy should be less costly to imple-
ment since it should not require close monitoring of escape-
ments during each fishing season.
-18-
v. Conclusions
While I have concentrated on the Skeena River as an
example, the methods outlined in this paper should be appli-
cable in many fisheries situations. The stochastic program-
ming solutions can be performed with any stock model that has
relatively few state variables (~7for modern computers), and
it is certainly possible to design more complex objective
functions to take a variety of cost and benefit factors into
account.
To summarize the previous sections:
(1) Stochastic dynamic programming provides a mechanism
for incorporating judgmental uncertainty about pro-
duction parameters into the design of optimal manage-
mental strategies.
(2) Optimal strategy curves (exploitation rate versus
stock size) are relatively insensitive to the judge-
mental probability distribution for the Ricker stock
production parameter.
(3) Optimal strategy curves are very sensitive to chang-
ing management objectives related to mean and variance
of catches.
(4) Strategies for reducing the variance of harvests
should also lead to higher and more predictable
stock sizes.
(5) Potential tradeoffs between mean and variance of
catches can be quantified along a Pareto Frontier
for decision negotiations.
-19-
(6) Simplified strategy curves can be developed that
give nearly optimal results.
Acknowledgements
The ideas in this paper are the result of discussions
with scientists at the International Institute for Applied
Systems Analysis, Vienna, especially Jim Bigelow, John Casti
and Sandra Buckingham. Special thanks to Peter Larkin and
F. E. A. Wood for suggesting the direction to look.
-20-
References
[lJ Allen, K. R. 1973. The influence of random fluctua-
tions in the stock-recruitment relationship on
the economic return from salmon fisheries. Con-
seil Internat. Pour L'Exploration De La Mer,
Rapport~164, pp 351-359.
[~ Bellman, R. 1961.
guided tour.
N. J.
Adaptive Control Processes: A
Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton,
[~ Bellman, R., and Dreyfus, S. 1962. Applied dynamic
programming. Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton,
N. J.
Bellman, R., and Kalaba, R. 1965. Dynamic Programming
and modern control theory. Academic Press, New
York.
Raiffa, H. 1968. Decision analysis: introductory
lectures on choices under uncertainty. Addison-
Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts.
[6J Ricker, W. E. 1964. Stock and recruitment. J. Fish.
Res. Bd. Canada, 11:559-623.
Ricker, W. E. 1973. Two mechanisms that make it im-
possible to maintain peak-period yields from
stocks of pacific salmon and other fishes. J.
Fish. Res. Bd. Canada, 30:1275-1286.
Shepard, M. P., Withler, F. C., McDonald, J., and
Aro, K. V. 1964. Further information on spawing
stock size and resultant production for Skeena
Sockeye. J. Fish. Res. Bd. Canada, 21:1329-31.
Tautz, A., Larkin, P. A., and Ricker, W. E. 1969.
Some effects of simulated long-term environ-
mental fluctuations on maximum sustained yield.
J. Fish. Res. Bd. Canada, 26:2715;26.
.19
3.6 .14
3.2
.44
036
42Q47 031
O.B 017 024
52~ 028
33 050
560038
0.4 043055
0
a 0.2 OJ. 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4
PARENT SPAWNERS (MILLION S)
2.8
2.4 018 04825 Cl090 040
057 015
2.0 070069
.10
013
063 067
060 ~20 .081.6 032 fil26 e68
e66 022 023c64J~ 027039 053021 34 54 065 0111.2 ~37 041
046 062
lJ)
z
o
H
.....J
.....J
~
~
U
o
r-
lJ)
r-
z
~
......J
::>
lJ)
llJ
a::
Figure 1. Stock-recruitment relationship for the Skeena
Sockeye. From Shepard, et ale (1964), with
recent points from unpublished data provided
by F. E. A. Wood, Environment Canada.
AL
TE
RN
AT
IV
E
DE
CI
SI
ON
S
ST
OC
HA
ST
IC
PO
SS
IB
IL
IT
IE
S
EX
PE
CT
ED
FU
TU
RE
RE
TU
RN
S
D
IS
C
R
ET
E
ST
O
C
K
S
IZ
E
EX
PL
O
IT
AT
IO
N
R
AT
E
=
0
E
X
P
lD
IT
A
n
O
N
r
.
.
I
RA
TE
=
0.1
EX
PL
O
IT
A
T
IO
N
R
AT
E
=
0.
2
I I I I I
O
TH
ER
R
AT
ES
N
EW
ST
O
CK
,
ON
E
EX
PE
CT
ED
FU
TU
RE
I
'
,
v
y
.
.
.
.
.
.
,
,
,
.
.
-
=
-!O
<=
.31
e.1
NE
W
ST
O
CK
,
SE
CO
ND
FU
TU
RE
I~~.6
\
1
ET
C.
I
I I I I
OT
HE
R
o
(S
F
ig
u
re
2.
D
ec
is
io
n
br
an
ch
es
a
n
d
p
ro
b
a
b
il
is
ti
c
o
u
tc
o
m
es
fo
r
a
n
y
s
ta
rt
in
g
s
to
c
k
s
iz
e
(e
xp
la
na
tio
n
in
te
s
t)
.
10
---U VALuE~ N.~ 194"0
• RECENT VALUES (1940-1970), (X:; 1.3
CX=1.5 (ALL DATA)
~
O~~~0::: 0W w~o:::
OlJ...
5
o
<0 0
% 1%
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 to 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2,6 28 3.0
OBSERVED VALUE OF 0.3
o 0.5 to 1.5
TRIAL VALUE OF ()(
OPTIMISTIC
(CX=1.5)
Figure 3. Observed distribution of the Ricker production
parameter a (equation 1) for Skeena River Sockeye,
and three judgmental probability distributions
for possible future values.
3.0
?O
1.0
0.
5
B
O
O
JE
CT
IV
E:
M
IN
(H
-
0.
6)
2
[]
]]
]
O
BJ
EC
TI
VE
:
M
IN
(H
-
-
to
)2
[:::
)':::
'.:]
OB
JE
CT
IV
E;
MA
X
H
O
I
I
P
8
1
.
/,
'
.
.
I
cc
i
a
'
-

I
I
o
0.
10.
4
0.5 0.
3
0.
2
0.60.70.
8
-
-
1
<
{ ~ t--t l- n..
.
oW l- ~ Z o ...... ~ ~ () -.J n.. X w
ST
OC
K
(M
ILL
IO
NS
OF
RE
CR
UI
TS
)
F
ig
u
re
4.
O
pt
im
al
h
ar
v
es
t
s
tr
a
te
g
ie
s
fo
r
th
re
e
d
if
fe
re
n
t
o
b
je
ct
iv
e
fu
n
ct
io
n
s,
u
s
in
g
th
e
o
p
ti
m
is
ti
c
(0
),
"
n
a
tu
ra
l"
(N
),
a
n
d
p
es
si
m
is
ti
c
(p
)
p
ro
b
ab
il
it
y
d
is
tr
ib
u
ti
o
n
s
o
f
F
ig
u
re
3.
0.5
0.4
0.3
FROM "NATURAL"
DISTRIBUTION
FOR ex
0.2
0.1
0,5
0.6 1.2
CATCH (MILLIONS)
1.8
0.4
USING NORMAL
DISTRIBUTION
FOR 0<
;U =1.3, cr =0.5
0.3
>-
.-
I--t
.....Jm 0.2
o
ce:
a.. 0.1
0.0 4 _
0.0
(H- 2m2
---
--
0.6 1.2
CATCH (MILLIONS)
H I:.I ", ,
....... -- __ J ,
1.8
Figure 5. Predicted probability distributions of catches
using the "natural" optimal strategies of Figure 4.
1.0 2.0 3.0
STOCK (RECRUITS, MILLIONS)
0.2"
>-J-
I--f 0.15o=Jm
<{(0
0
0::: 0.10CL
0
W
l- 0.05u~
L.LJ
a:
a...
0.0
0.0
USING MAX H
STRATEGY~ , .....
,,';' ,
,," --:;;;::~
USING (H- 2.)2 /'~/
STRATEGY ----,~
I
"
USING (H-.612
~ STRATEGY
USING (H - 1.)2
STRATEGY
Figure 6. Predicted probability distribution of stock sizes
associated with the catches of Figure 5.
3.00.5 1.0 2.0
STOCK (MILLIONS OF RECRUITS)
0.0 +--.L--&---tL--....a..-4--r------...,........-----~
o
0.7
0.1
O.B
0..6
UJ
I-
« 0.5
0:::
z
o 0.4
~
I-
«
I- 0.3
........
o
.--J
~ 0.2
w
Figure 7. Optimal strategies for different objectives com-
pared to actual management practice on the Skeena
River, to the optimal fixed ascapement policy,
and to a simplified alternative.
19
50
-1
97
4
~
O
BS
ER
VE
O
.v
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
DE
VI
AT
IO
N
OF
CA
TC
HE
S
(M
ILL
ION
S)
"
FN
RO
NT
IE
R
AS
SU
M
IN
G
AT
UR
AL
"
0-
::
FO
R
ex
D1
ST
Rl
ElJ
TIO
N
0-.
.,.~':""
'\""""
""'\l.
I.~
"
""~
~"'"'
:
IH
-d
'
.
,
H
ST
RA
TE
GY
,,
~~
"
"
-
.
~
ST
RA
TE
GY
CO
NS
TA
NT
0<.
""-.':
.,,'
:.
SI~~
~TED
~5CAP
EMENT
L~
~
EO
ST
RA
TE
GY
TR
AT
EG
Y
/.....
0(H
-1
)2
S
I'
:.':
...
.':
.
TR
AT
EG
Y
I~ ~
,to
"
-
.
"
(H
-
.
6)2
0.6
4
6~S
TR
ATE
GY
0.0
0'1
..
.A
X
"
,
"

-
-
-
:
:
;
'~~~
G~
~-
"
,
S~NM
RD
I
1.
0
- V
) z 0 t--
t
-
-
.
J
-
-
.
J ~ - [5
0.
8
I- « u z U1 ~ Fig
u
re
8.
P
ar
et
o
F
ro
n
ti
er
fo

b
es
t
p
o
ss
ib
le
c
o
m
bi
na
ti
on
s
o
f
m
e
a
n
a
n
d
v
a
r
ia
n
ce
o
f
c
a
tc
h
es
,
fo
r
th
e
S
ke
en
a
R
iv
er
(e
xp
la
na
tio
n
in
te
x
t)
.
2.01.6
USING CONSTANT
ESCAPEMEN T STRA"TEGY
,\/
I \
I
\ ,\
\ I \ "\/ \ f'j ~ .....,
\..... '/ --,
\
\
1.2
(MILLIONS)
r-,
I ,
I \
r ../ \
I \
" I \
" I \
.... "'-\ ...-
0.4 0.8
CATCH
o
0.0
.07
.06
.05
>- .04
0 t-
-~~ .03 1\
u OO J

.02 ,/om ,_/
WQ /
Q:O:: ... J
a.. a.. .01 I
"'/J
...
I
I
T
0.4 0.8 1.2 1,6 2.0
CATCH (MILLIONS)
Figure 9. Predicted probability distributions of catches
using the simplified strategy curve in Figure 7
as opposed to the best fixed escapement strategy.
Recent actual catches are shown for comparison.
51作业君

Email:51zuoyejun

@gmail.com

添加客服微信: abby12468