辅导案例-ECON6002

欢迎使用51辅导,51作业君孵化低价透明的学长辅导平台,服务保持优质,平均费用压低50%以上! 51fudao.top
ECON6002 Macroeconomics Analysis 1
Week 1: “The Solow-Swan Model”
Christopher Gibbs
University of Sydney
Semester 1, 2020
Class Outline
1 Course overview
2 Mathematics review
3 5-minute break
4 Solow-Swan model
5 Solving the model
6 5-minute break
7 Using the model
8 Summary
Readings: Unit of Study Outline; Romer, Chapter 1
Course Overview
• This course focuses on the main macroeconomic models
used to understand theoretical mechanisms behind
long-run growth, business cycles, monetary policy, fiscal
policy, and consumption
• We will learn how to solve and use these models, as well as
apply them to policy-relevant issues
• Textbook: David Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, 4th or
5th Edition, McGraw Hill
Topics
1 Economic Growth (Weeks 1-2)
2 Real Business Cycles (Weeks 5 and 6)
3 Money and the Business Cycle (week 8 - 11)
4 Fiscal Policy and Consumption (Weeks 12 - 13... we may
not get all the way here)
In-class midterm exam in Week 7 (8 April)
Other Course Details
• Tutorial questions will be posted on Canvas with online
discussion board and video solutions by the online tutor
(Tristan Truuvert)
- Tutor will also respond to questions in ED
- Please use ED. You are more than welcome to answer each
others questions!
• Three problem sets will also be posted on Canvas and may
be turned in online until week 7. After week 7, all
assignments are due in class.
• Consultation hours: Wednesday 2-4pm, Social Science
Building, Room 563
• Email: [email protected]
- Use ED to send me general questions. You are likely not
the only person with the question you are asking. Create
public goods!
Mathematics Review
Math(s)
• This course is centered around building “simple”
mathematical models to describe economic phenomena
• You will be expected to be able to manipulate the models
to analyse economic policies
• We will walk through the basics of the mathematical tools
we will need to solve each model
• I only expect you to understand the concepts well enough
that you can do the economics
• If you want an excellent reference for the math that we will
use in the course I recommend:
- Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, by
Alpha C. Chiang and Kevin Wainwright
Math(s)
• What math do we need to study growth? That depends on
the questions...
Math(s)... and aside on the growth
Figure: Source: Maddison (2008)
Math(s)
• What math do we need to study growth? That depends on
the questions...
• For questions about growth rates, we need to study
differential equations
First-order linear differential equations
dy
dt
+ u(t)y = w(t) (1)
• The number of derivatives of a function y determines the
order
- It may enter though in powers, e.g. (dy/dt)2
- The highest power obtained in the equation is known as the
degree
• No product of y and dy/dt occurs so the above is linear
• u(t) and w(t) are functions of t and may take on any form
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
dy
dt
+ ay = 0 (2)
• If u and w are constants, w = 0, and a is some constant, we
say that the dif. eq. is homogeneous
• The defining characteristic of a homogeneous dif. eq. is
that if all terms are multiplied by a constant, the equation
remains homogeneous
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Key questions here are:
- Why should I care?
- If I do care, how do I solve such an equation?
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Q: Has economic growth been constant over the last 1000
years or has it been accelerating?
• A: ?
• Well, let’s build a simple model of constant technological
growth and find out
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Q: Has economic growth been constant over the last 1000
years or has it been accelerating?
• A: ?
• Well, let’s build a simple model of constant technological
growth and find out
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Modeling constant technological growth
- Let A(t) be the stock of technology at time t
- Let g be the growth rate of technology
dA
dt
= gA(t) (3)
- rearranged, we get
dA
dt
− gA(t) = 0 (4)
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
dA
dt
− gA = 0 (5)
• A question of interest in this case is how does technology
evolve over time?
• To answer, we need to solve the above homogeneous linear
dif. eq.
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• To solve, we need to recover a function whose derivative is
(6)
dA
dt
− gA = 0 (6)
• In general, this often requires a person to just be clever and
have a good recall of common derivatives and integrals
• Luckily, there is a common one that solves pretty much any
problem you will encounter in economics
- The natural logarithm: lnX
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Let’s differentiate lnX with respect to time. To do so, we
need to apply the chain rule...
1 We take the derivative of lnX w.r.t. X evaluated at X
dlnX
dX
=
1
X
2 We then take the derivative of X with respect to time
dX
dt
=
dX
dt
3 Finally, we multiply the two together
dlnX
dt
=
1
X
dX
dt
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Now, the following math magic where I replace X with A
dA
dt
− gA = 0
dA
dt
= gA
1
A
dA
dt
= g
dlnA
dt
= g
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Now, the following math magic where I replace X with A
dA
dt
− gA = 0
dA
dt
= gA
1
A
dA
dt
= g
dlnA
dt
= g
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Integrate with respect to t

dlnA
dt
dt =

gdt
lnA(t) = c+ gt
- c is an unknown constant
• This already says something interesting: growth is log
linear!
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
• Now, exponentiate both sides
elnA(t) = ec+gt
A(t) = ecegt
A(t) = Cegt (7)
- (7) is called the general solution. It is general because we
have the arbitrary constant C, which is still unknown.
- When we substitute in value for C, (7) becomes a particular
solution.
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
A(t) = Cegt
• To find C, we need an additional piece of information.
• In economics, this piece of information is usually provided
by economic theory and the modeling context.
• For example, the obvious C to choose here is A(0) or the
initial level of technology assumed for the economy.
A(t) = A(0)egt
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
A(t) = A(0)egt
• Therefore, we have assumed exponential growth...
• How does this assumption match up with the data?
Math(s)... and aside on the growth
First-order linear differential equations:
homogeneous case
Figure: Source: Maddison (2008)
First-order linear differential equations:
nonhomogeneous case
dy
dt
+ ay = b (8)
• The nonhomogeneous case follows straight from the
homogeneous case
• The solution here is the sum of two terms: the
complementary function and the particular integral
• The solution in fact is just a particular solution of the
general solution to the homogeneous case
First-order linear differential equations:
nonhomogeneous case
• The general solution or complementary function:
yc = Ce
−at (9)
• The particular solution or integral: Suppose dy/dt = 0
ay = b
or
yp =
b
a
First-order linear differential equations:
nonhomogeneous case
y(t) = yc + yp = Ce
−at +
b
a
(10)
• Finally, using the initial condition y(0), we have
y(0) = Ce−a×0 +
b
a
= C +
b
a⇒
C = y(0)− b
a
y(t) =
[
y(0)− b
a
]
e−at +
b
a
(11)
Nonlinear differential equations:
first order and first degree
dy
dt
= h(y, t) (12)
• This is first order because we have only a first derivative
• It is first degree because we do not consider powers of dy/dt
• But there is no restriction on the power of y.
Nonlinear differential equations:
first order and first degree
• Let’s consider a special case here that is particularly
relevant for economics
dy
dt
= h(y, t)
dy
dt
= Ty(t)m −Ry(t)
- Where T and R are constants and m 6= 0 or 1
Nonlinear differential equations:
first order and first degree
• In this case, we can use the time honoured tradition of a
change in variables to reduce the system to something we
already know how to solve
y−m
dy
dt
+Ry1−m = T
• Let z = y1−m, then
dz
dt
=
dz
dy
dy
dt
= (1−m)y−mdy
dt
• and math magic
1
1−m
dz
dt
+Rz = T (13)
Nonlinear differential equations:
first order and first degree
1
1−m
dz
dt
+Rz = T
• This my friends, we know how to solve... just rearrange
dz
dt
+ (1−m)Rz = (1−m)T (14)
• It is just a nonhomogeneous first-order linear differential
equations, which we saw just a few slides ago and which is
straight forward to solve!
A note on notation
• A common way to write time derivatives is
dx
dt
= x˙
- To save time and space, I (and Romer) use the ‘dot’ to
denote the time derivative of a variable
• Also, it is common to drop the t in state variables. For
example,
A(t) = A
The Solow-Swan Model
Model Structure
• Technology and population growth are exogenous
• Capital accumulation and output are endogenous
• One good, closed economy, no government spending, no
unemployment, constant saving rate
• Perfectly competitive markets
Key Assumption #1:
An Aggregate Production Function
• Y (t) = F (K(t), A(t)L(t))
• Y=output, K=capital, L=labour, and A=effectiveness of
labour
• Multiplicative interaction of A and L corresponds to
“labour-augmenting” technological change, no trend in
K/Y ratio
• Constant returns to scale: F (cK, cAL) = cF (K,AL)
• Implies no relevant fixed inputs (e.g., land) or further gains
from specialization
• Replication principle (same setup on Mars)
• Also, considerable empirical evidence that a c.r.s. aggregate
production function is a useful predictive construct
Intensive Form
• y = f(k)
• y=output per unit of effective labour (Y/AL) and
k=capital per unit of effective labour (K/AL)
• Follows from c.r.s. with c = 1AL ⇒ F ( KAL , 1) = 1ALF (K,AL)
• Model can be more easily solved using intensive form given
an implied “steady state” in k and y
Mathematical Properties and an Example
• f(0) = 0, f ′(k) > 0, and f ′′(k) < 0
• Marginal product of capital is positive, but subject to
diminishing returns
• Additional “Inada” conditions: limk→0f ′(k) =∞ and
limk→∞f ′(k) = 0
• Cobb-Douglas example: y = kα, where 0 < α < 1
• f(0) = 0, f ′(k) = αkα−1 > 0, and
f ′′(k) = (α− 1)αkα−2 < 0
• α ends up being equivalent to the capital share of income
in the model, while the empirical share historically in most
countries has been around one-third (0.33)
Cobb-Douglas Production Function
Key Assumption #2:
Exogenous Processes
• Solow-Swan model assumes constant growth rates for
population and technology
• L˙(t) = nL(t)
• A˙(t) = gA(t)
• n=population growth rate and g=technology growth rate
Key Assumption #3:
Capital Accumulation Identity
• Households save a fraction of income to invest in new
capital, but existing capital depreciates by a fixed rate
• K˙(t) = sY (t)− δK(t)
• s=saving rate and δ=depreciation rate
• 0 < s < 1 and n+ g + δ > 0
• In Chapter 2, we will make savings endogenous, but many
results remain robust
Model Solution
• Step 1: Solve for behaviour of capital and output using
production function, exogenous processes, capital
accumulation identity
- Differentiate k = KAL with respect to time (chain-rule +
quotient-rule calculus)
k˙ =

AL
− K
[AL]2
[AL˙+ LA˙] =

AL
− K
AL

L
− K
AL

A
Model Solution
• Step 2: Substitute the model assumptions to simply the
following equation:
k˙ =

AL
− K
AL

L
− K
AL

A
- K˙ = sY − δK
- YAL = y = f(k)
- L˙L = n
- A˙A = g
k˙ = sf(k)− (n+ g + δ)k
Model Solution
• Step 2: Substitute the model assumptions to simply the
following equation:
k˙ =

AL
− K
AL

L
− K
AL

A
- K˙ = sY − δK
- YAL = y = f(k)
- L˙L = n
- A˙A = g
k˙ = sf(k)− (n+ g + δ)k
The Solow-Swan Model in a Single Picture
Solving for Steady State and Balanced Growth Path
• Given k > 0, unique steady state k∗ for capital per unit of
effective labour
• k˙ > 0 if k < k∗ and k˙ < 0 if k > k∗ (also see phase diagram)
• Given initial endowment of capital k(0) 6= k∗, implies
transition dynamics in which output growth depends on
capital accumulation
• But also implies “balanced growth path” in steady state in
which all inputs (capital, labour, and technology) and
output grow at constant rates
• K and Y grow at rate n+ g while K/L and Y/L grow at
rate g (i.e., output per capita grows at the rate of change
in technology)
• Capital-output (K/Y ) ratio remains constant at level that
depends on k∗
Uniqueness of Steady State
Policy Question
• What if the government encouraged people to save at a
higher rate: sNEW > sOLD?
• Increases the steady-state k and y
• But consumption would initially fall in the transition and
not clear if it would increase in steady state
• “Golden Rule” saving rate is the one that maximizes
consumption in steady state
• If Golden Rule capital stock is above current capital stock,
we would have to sacrifice consumption today for higher
consumption for future generations
Policy Question Answers in the Model
• We answer these questions by looking at the endogenous
response of the model to an exogenous change in a
parameter.
• We do this in two ways:
1. Graphically, using the Solow-Swan Diagram
2. Using math to derive algebraic relationships and calculus to
look at the effects of small changes of parameters
Graphically: Increase in Saving Rate
Graphically: Transition dynamics
Math: Impact of Saving Rate on Consumption in
Steady State
• c∗ = f(k∗)− (n+ g + δ)k∗
• Because steady-state capital k∗ depends on saving rate s,
we can implicitly solve
∂c∗
∂s
= [f ′(k∗)− (n+ g + δ)]∂k

∂s
• At the “Golden Rule” max, ∂c∗∂s = 0
• I.e., sGR is such that f ′(k∗GR) = n+ g + δ
• Slope of the (intensive) production function is the same as
the (constant) slope of the break-even investment function
Goldilocks and the Three Bears
Speed of Convergence?
• To think about speed of convergence, solve for the
adjustment of capital near steady state
• First-order (linear) Taylor-series approx of
k˙ = sf(k)− (n+ g + δ)k at steady state k = k∗:
k˙ ≈
[
∂k˙
∂k
|k=k∗
]
(k − k∗)
Linear approximations
• Taylor series approximations: we can approximate any real
function f(x) about a point x = a using the following
f(x) = f(a) + f ′(a)(x− a) + f
′′(a)
2!
(x− a)2 + f
′′′(a)
3!
(x− a)3
+....+
f (n)(a)
n!
(x− a)n + ....
• If want a linear approximation, we just need
f(x) = f(a) + f ′(a)(x− a)
Speed of Convergence?
• To think about speed of convergence, solve for the
adjustment of capital near steady state
• Adjustment coefficient:
∂k˙
∂k
|k=k∗ = sf ′(k∗)− (n+ g + δ)
=
(n+ g + δ)k∗f ′(k∗)
f(k∗)
− (n+ g + δ)
= (α(k∗)− 1)(n+ g + δ)
• where α(k∗) is the capital share of income, which is about
one-third in the data
• Thus, pop growth=1%, tech growth=2%, and
depreciation=3% ⇒ 4% convergence per year
Grains of Truth and Grains of Salt
• Capital accumulation does seem to be subject to
diminishing returns (e.g., Soviet Union)
• Some support for convergence, but seems to be within
groups of countries with similar characteristics
(“conditional convergence”)
• Growth accounting suggests differences in physical capital
explain about one-third of the variation in output per
capita across countries
• But the remaining two-thirds is attributed to the nebulous
“Solow residual” that may or may not capture exogenous
technology growth
• Solow-Swan model implies lower pop growth would lead to
higher k∗ and faster growth in the transition
- No empirical support for this (endogenous growth models
typically have opposite prediction)
Evidence of Convergence using Ex Post Selection of
Countries
Evidence of Convergence using Ex Post Selection of
Countries
• What is wrong with this analysis?
Selection
- Countries that have data to use for such an exercise are
usually rich today
- Poor countries in 1870 that are still poor today don’t have
reliable data and are excluded from the sample
- Measurement error is also a problem
Evidence of Convergence using Ex Post Selection of
Countries
• What is wrong with this analysis? Selection
- Countries that have data to use for such an exercise are
usually rich today
- Poor countries in 1870 that are still poor today don’t have
reliable data and are excluded from the sample
- Measurement error is also a problem
Evidence of Convergence using Ex Ante Selection of
Countries
Evidence of Convergence Weighting by Size of Country
Does(Income(per(capita(“converge”?(
CHAPTER(1(((IntroducKon(to(
Macroeconomics(
- 14 -


Bourguignon and
Morrisson (2002)
conclude that the
inequality of global
income worsened from
the start of the nineteenth
century until the end of
World War II “and after
that seems to have
stabilized or to have
grown more slowly”.40

Where does that
leave us on both poverty
and the global
distribution of income?
Poverty rates have been
declining, especially in Asia. So very likely has the absolute number of those living at
below one dollar a day. Increasingly, global poverty is being concentrated in Africa. At
the same time, poverty rates have not declined much in Latin America in recent decades.
Taking account of other social indicators, as reflected in the Human Development Index,
presents a more encouraging picture of the changing fortunes of the poorest, but the HIV-
AIDS epidemic is taking a sad toll on longevity in Africa.

Income distribution developments are more mixed. There has been a growing
divergence among national average incomes. Inequality has risen within many countries.
But it is likely that inequality among the world’s citizens declined during the last decades
of the twentieth century. However we should not take too much comfort from that, for as
Sala-i-Martin (2002a) points out, “Unless Africa starts growing in the near future, …
income inequalities will start rising again.”


III. The Policy Issues

Trade and growth. Trade policy has long been central to economic policy choices. In
the early post-World War II period, the theory of import-substituting industrialization
(ISI) dominated among developing countries, and its implementation for some time
seemed to produce positive results. Then as time went by, it was observed both that
countries that has pursued export promotion strategies were more successful than those
that focused on keeping imports out, and that the returns to ISI seemed to be diminishing.

40 However, Milanovic (1999) finds that global income inequality increased between 1988 and 1993, in part
because of growing gaps between rural and urban incomes in China. By contrast, Bhalla (2002) shows
world inequality in 2002 at its lowest level in the post-World War II period, a result of the much greater
reductions in global poverty in the 1990s that his methodology produces. Similarly, Sala -i-Martin (2002a)
finds massive decreases in global inequality at the individual level between 1980 and 1998.

Figure 5. Real GDP per capita*, 1980-2000, average annual
growth on initial level (area proportional to population in 1980)
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-5,000 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 30,000
Real GDP per capita*,1980
Ra
te
of
Gr
ow
th
of
Re
al
GD
P p
er
ca
pit
a*
,
19
80
-2
00
0 (
pe
rce
nt
pe
r y
ea
r)
Sub-Saharan AfricaChina
U.S.A.India
*Real GDP in U.S.$ per equivalent adult. Source: Penn World Tables, version 6.1
Summary
• Solow-Swan model solves for endogenous capital
accumulation as a function of initial endowment of capital,
saving rate, pop growth, tech growth, depreciation
• Model predicts transition dynamics and steady state
• Can be used to consider policy questions and make
quantitative predictions about things like speed of
convergence
• Model produces profound insights about long-run growth,
but empirical support is mixed
• Next time: Microfoundations for growth models (Romer,
Chapter 2)
51作业君

Email:51zuoyejun

@gmail.com

添加客服微信: abby12468